The final installment of the conversation, here Justin Schlosberg responds to Rob Kenny's article.
In response to my brief on media ownership limits, Rob Kenny
helpfully moves the discussion forward by questioning some of the claims and
detail in that brief. Before offering my response in kind, it is important to
make clear Rob’s interest as a member of the Communications Chambers, which
includes News Corporation among their list of clients, particularly as much of
his arguments are made with a focus on Rupert Murdoch’s news assets. (I myself
declared in an interest at the outset of my brief to which Rob responds,
stating that I have been actively involved in preparing evidence on behalf of
the Media Reform Coalition).
With that out the way, I will now turn to Rob’s response which is important
because it reflects the prevailing opinion among commercial media lobbyists in
response to any fundamental change in the status quo of ownership regulation.
Rob understandably focuses on a crucial question in this debate: would a system
of fixed ownership limits along the lines proposed in my brief necessarily
threaten growth and competitiveness, particularly in ailing newspaper markets?
He highlights that my brief comes out in favour of a firm ‘no’ to this
question. But he takes issue with this finding in two areas. First, he points
out that:
Both the Mail and the Sun have shares of the national newspaper market of over
20%. Thus under the MRC’s rules, both these titles would need to be publicly
floated as independent entities.
He then remarks on the associated costs and risks of a public floatation and
suggests that these would pose an additional threat to the stability and sustainability
of newspaper markets. But it is not quite clear whether he is suggesting that a
public floatation is part of rules advocated by the Media Reform Coalition
(MRC), or whether a public floatation would be a necessary consequence of any
attempt to dilute a controlling interest in a dominant media group. In any
case, neither claim is quite accurate. First, MRC rules do not specify the need
for floatation and second, it is quite conceivable that alternative remedies
and means could be used to achieve the overall objectives of fixed ownership
limits along the lines reflected on in my brief. Indeed, Rob goes on to address
these alternatives in the second area that he focuses on, in respect of Sky’s
overwhelming control of the wholesale market in commercial radio news. He
points out that
In such cases [Justin’s paper] allows that “an equity carve-out or the
transferral of voting rights from shareholders to employees’ would be
appropriate”
He goes on to question the practicality of the first alternative on the basis
that no one would likely “be interested in owning any number of shares
that had no prospect of paying dividends, but rather required constant
subsidies”. This claim is questionable. There are certainly examples in other
industries of civil society groups taking up the opportunity to own shares in
companies as a means of holding them to account ethically, including the oil
and arms industries. But even if this was not feasible for any reason, Rob’s
critique of the alternative – transferring voting rights to employees – is more
problematic.
His arguments rest on a somewhat dubious set of assumptions and misconceptions
about the ‘practical benefit’ of such a measure in terms of enhancing editorial
independence, and the potential costs in terms of a threat to sustainability
which “could put Sky News’ life at stake”. Such hyperbole is reflective of a
general discourse of fear that routinely emanates from commercial media amidst
the prospect of ownership regulatory intervention. For one thing, it is not
clear why targeting the overwhelming dominance of Sky News Radio should
threaten the viability of Sky News as a whole. But more acutely, Rob seems to
dismiss out of hand just the kind of potential remedies that were acceptable to
none other than Newscorp themselves in the build up to their proposed merger
with BskyB in 2011. During that process, plurality concerns raised by Ofcom
resulted in the suggestion that Sky News could be ‘spun off’ if the deal was to
be approved with a prescribed limit on Newscorp’s stake. This was to be
accompanied by the establishment of an editorial board made up of a majority of
independent directors (with no other Newscorp interests), responsible for
ensuring the news channel’s editorial autonomy and integrity. The latter undertaking
constitutes precisely the kind of public interest obligations advocated by MRC
and other civil society groups, in addition to structural remedies aimed at
reducing proprietor’s direct influence over news making.
Of course, Rob is right to suggest that such measures offer no panacea to the
problems of media power exposed at the Leveson hearings. It is certainly
conceivable that more robust forms of intervention might be considered compared
to the undertakings accepted for the Newscorp-BSkyB merger (or that which has
long already existed in respect of Rupert Murdoch’s purchase of the Times and
Sunday Times newspapers in 1981). But he is simply wrong to suggest that any
potential benefits would be outweighed by the assumed costs in respect of
innovation or growth. Newspaper owners themselves – including both the Murdochs
and Daily Mail owner Viscount Rothermere – were at pains to stress to Leveson
that they considered editorial independence to be ‘good for business’. Rob
himself argues elsewhere that the editorial influence of proprietors is waning
amidst competing influences over content stemming from social media, as well as
financial pressures. The implication is that the exercise of editorial
influence by proprietors is in conflict with strategies of commercial survival
and success – in effect, the inverse of what he is arguing here. There is
certainly no evidence to suggest that holding proprietors true to their word by
formalizing editorial independence would incur any costs for growth or innovation
at all.
Yet there is considerable evidence to the contrary. In fact, in several areas
where there has been sustained and unchecked growth in ownership concentration
within news markets, there has been a concomitant fall in standards, quality
and ultimately, consumer demand. This was well documented in the US by Pew research just this year
and has been similarly demonstrated in the UK in
respect of the rapidly converging local and regional news market.
Perhaps most concerning of all, Rob makes no mention of the social and
democratic costs in respect of the intimate relations between media and
political elites laid bare at the Leveson hearings. There is a reason why
owners of smaller media groups do not – like Murdoch - get regular invites for
tea at number 10 (and leave by the back door), or – like Rothermere – get to
spend ‘private’ weekends with the Prime Minister at Chequers as he did last
year. The reality is that whether or not consumption or exposure diversity is
improving or getting worse (and we can cherry pick data to argue the case
either way), size matters in respect of media power. If we are to place any
value on democratic health as opposed to just competitive health of markets,
then we need real plurality reform to address the real and existing
accumulations of that power.
OurKingdom is grateful to the LSE blog for allowing us to crosspost this piece.